100% satisfaction guarantee Immediately available after payment Both online and in PDF No strings attached
logo-home
Samenvatting Microeconomics: theory and analysis $7.33   Add to cart

Summary

Samenvatting Microeconomics: theory and analysis

 36 views  1 purchase
  • Course
  • Institution
  • Book

College aantekeningen, met slides en eventuele extra notities en berekeningen van het van Microeconomics: theory and analysis Dit bevat alle stof die je moet kennen voor dit vak, het 'kunnen' gedeelte zit hem vooral in de instructie- en werkcolleges. Voor dit vak zijn de instructiecolleges en we...

[Show more]

Preview 5 out of 60  pages

  • No
  • Alle stof nodig voor het tentamen
  • January 10, 2023
  • 60
  • 2022/2023
  • Summary
avatar-seller
Microeconomics theory and analysis

Lecture 1 & 2 Consumer Choice
“People choose the best bundle they can afford”

What can you afford?
- Budget constraint (Chapter 2)
What is the best bundle?
- Preferences (Chapter 3)
How to model preferences?
- Utility functions (Chapter 4)
What to choose?
- Choice (Chapter 5)

Budget constraint
● let us say there are two goods x1 and x2 with prices p1 and p2
● consumer has income m
● a consumption bundle is (x1, x2)
● the budget constraint defines what a consumer can afford:
○ p1x1 + p2x2 ≤ m
● everything that is affordable lies within the budget set
● the set of consumption bundles that cost exactly m form the
budget line
○ p1x1 + p2x2 = m

What happens if the income decreases from m to m’?
note: the slope does not change since prices are the same




What happens if the price of good 1 increases?

,To sum up
● a change in income causes a parallel shift of the budget line → the slope does not
change
● if the price of one good changes, this changes the slope of the budget line
𝑝1
● slope is: − 𝑝2
● If p1 ↑ → slope increases If p1 ↓ → slope decreases
● If p2 ↑→ slope decreases If p2 ↓ → slope increases

Preferences
● consumers choose between consumption bundles
● consider two bundles X = (x1, x2) and Y = (y1, y2)
● if X is strictly preferred to Y, we write:
○ (x1, x2) ≻ (y1, y2)
● if the consumer is indifferent between X and Y, we write:
○ (𝑥1, 𝑥2) ∼ (𝑦1, 𝑦2)
● if x is weakly preferred to Y, we write:
○ (𝑥1, 𝑥2) ≽ (𝑦1, 𝑦2)

Three usual assumptions about preferences
● complete. Any two bundles can be compared
○ (x1, x2) ≽(y1, y2) or (y1, y2) ≽ (x1, x2) or both
● reflexive. Any bundle is at least as good as itself
○ (x1,x2) ≽ (x1, x2)
● transitive. If (x1, x2) ≽ (y1, y2) and (y1, y2) ≽ (z1, z2)
then (x1, x2) ≽ (z1, z2)

Preferences can graphically be described by indifference curves
All bundles the lie on an indifference curve are equally good (the consumer is indifferent)

indifferences curves can have many shapes but they cannot cross
why?
1. X ~ Z
2. Z ~ Y
● by transitivity it should be that: X ~ Y
● but X and Y are not on the same indifference curve so
the consumer is not indifferent between them!

Perfect substitutes
● two goods are substitutes if the consumer is willing to
substitute one good for the other at a constant rate
○ for me consuming two apples is the same as consuming one orange
● two goods are perfect substitutes if the consumer is willing to substitute the goods
on a one-to-one basis
○ for me, consuming one apple is the same as consuming one orange. So i
am indifferent between consuming two apples, two oranges, and one apple
and one orange

,Perfect substitutes
● the consumer prefers bundles on higher indifference curves to
bundles on lower indifference curves
● that is, the consumer prefers changes in the direction of the
arrows
● slope: -1 (straight line because of the constant rate)




Perfect complements
● complements are goods that are always consumed in fixed
proportions
● perfect complements are goods that are always consumed
one of each
● they ‘complement’ each other
● example: right shoe and left shoe




Bads
● a bad is a commodity that the consumer does not like
● in this example good 2 is a bad


Preferences
● of it is convenient to assume that preferences are
‘well-behaved’
● in this case, we make two further assumptions
● monotonicity. more is better
○ if 𝑥1 ≥ 𝑦1 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑥2 > 𝑦2, 𝑡ℎ𝑒𝑛 (𝑥1, 𝑥2) ≻ (𝑦1, 𝑦2)
● convexity. averages are preferred (to extremes)
○ if (x1, x2) ~ (y1, y2) then 𝑡𝑥1 + (1 − 𝑡)𝑦1 ≽ (𝑥1, 𝑥2)
○ for any t between 0 and 1

If preferences are monotonic:
● more of both goods means a better bundle
● less of both goods mean a worse bundle
● indifference curves have a negative slope
● indifference curves further from the origin represent
better bundles

If preferences are convex:
● averages are preferred to extremes
● all of the weighted averages of X and Y are
weakly preferred to X and Y

,Utility
● preferences can be described by a utility function
● a utility function assigns a number to a bundle such that better bundles get higher
numbers (i.e. a higher utility)
○ (x1, x2) ~ (y1, y2) if and only if u(x1, x2) = u(y1, y2)
● and
○ (𝑥1, 𝑥2) ≻ (𝑦1, 𝑦2) 𝑖𝑓 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑜𝑛𝑙𝑦 𝑖𝑓 𝑢(𝑥1, 𝑥2) > 𝑢(𝑦1, 𝑦2)

● for a utility function to represent preferences, the only thing that matters is the order
of the bundles
● the value themselves have no meaning apart from the order.
● for example, if u(A) = 1 and u(B) = 2, it does not mean that B is twice as good as A. It
only means that the consumer prefers B to A
● this is called ordinal utility
● this also implies that there are many utility functions that represent the same
preferences

● in fact, any (positive) monotonic transformation of the utility function is allowed
● a monotonic transformation transforms each number such that the order is preserved
● examples:
○ adding or subtracting a number
■ 𝑓1(𝑢1) = 𝑢1 + 10
○ multiplication by a positive number
■ 𝑓2(𝑢1) = 2𝑢1
○ raising each number by an odd power
3
■ 𝑓3(𝑢1) = (𝑢1)
● all of these functions represent the same preferences as u1

● on an indifference curve, all bundles are valued equally
● hence the utility of all the bundles on an indifference curve
must be the same
● e.g. suppose u(x1, x2) = x1x2 = k

● preferences determine the shape of the indifference curve
● this means that any monotonic transformation of a utility function will not change the
shape of the indifference curves
● example: u(x1, x2) = 2x1x2 = 2k

● a widely used type of utility functions are Cobb-Douglas utility
functions
𝑐 𝑑
○ 𝑢(𝑥1, 𝑥2) = 𝑥1 𝑥2 where c and d are positive numbers
● they describe well-behaved preferences and have more convenient
properties

, ● with quasilinear preferences, utility is linear in one good and
nonlinear in the other good:
○ 𝑢(𝑥1, 𝑥2) = 𝑣1(𝑥1) + 𝑥2

𝑢(𝑥1, 𝑥2) = 𝑥1 + 𝑥2
● in this case, indifference curves are vertically shifted versions of
each other




● How does utility change if you receive a little more of good 1?
● this rate of change is called the marginal utility of good 1:
δ𝑢(𝑥1, 𝑥2)
○ 𝑀𝑈1 = δ𝑥1
● so, the change in utility associated with a change in consumption of good 1 is
○ 𝑑𝑈 = 𝑀𝑈1𝑑𝑥1


● the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) measure the slope of an
indifference curve
● what does this mean?
● the MRS indicates the rate at which a consumer is willing to
substitute two goods

Some remarks regarding 𝑀𝑅𝑆𝑥 𝑥
1 2

● the x1x2 under the MRS means marginal rate of substitution of x1 for x2
● it is the amount of x2 which a consumer can exchange for one unit of x1 to stay on
the same indifference curve
● for example, if 𝑀𝑅𝑆𝑥 𝑥 = 2 means
1 2
𝑥1
○ 𝑥2
= 2 ⇒ 𝑥1 = 2𝑥2
● that is, 1 unit of x1 is worth 2 units of x2 to this consumer
● the consumer will give up 2 units of x2 to obtain 1 additional unit of x1 and will stay
on the same indifference curve
In the subscript of MRS, always put the good on the horizontal axis first!

● the MRS is equal to the ratio of the marginal utilities:
𝑀𝑈1
○ 𝑀𝑅𝑆𝑥 𝑥 = 𝑀𝑈2
1 2

The benefits of buying summaries with Stuvia:

Guaranteed quality through customer reviews

Guaranteed quality through customer reviews

Stuvia customers have reviewed more than 700,000 summaries. This how you know that you are buying the best documents.

Quick and easy check-out

Quick and easy check-out

You can quickly pay through credit card or Stuvia-credit for the summaries. There is no membership needed.

Focus on what matters

Focus on what matters

Your fellow students write the study notes themselves, which is why the documents are always reliable and up-to-date. This ensures you quickly get to the core!

Frequently asked questions

What do I get when I buy this document?

You get a PDF, available immediately after your purchase. The purchased document is accessible anytime, anywhere and indefinitely through your profile.

Satisfaction guarantee: how does it work?

Our satisfaction guarantee ensures that you always find a study document that suits you well. You fill out a form, and our customer service team takes care of the rest.

Who am I buying these notes from?

Stuvia is a marketplace, so you are not buying this document from us, but from seller Dee25. Stuvia facilitates payment to the seller.

Will I be stuck with a subscription?

No, you only buy these notes for $7.33. You're not tied to anything after your purchase.

Can Stuvia be trusted?

4.6 stars on Google & Trustpilot (+1000 reviews)

79064 documents were sold in the last 30 days

Founded in 2010, the go-to place to buy study notes for 14 years now

Start selling
$7.33  1x  sold
  • (0)
  Add to cart